Monetizing Apples And Oranges

Let me start by thanking Richard Tol, Marcel Crok, and everyone involved in the ongoing discussion at the post called “The Bogus Cost of Carbon”. In particular, Richard Tol has explained and defended his point of view, giving us an excellent example of science at work.

In that post I discussed the “SCC”, the so-called “Social Cost of Carbon”. There are many things I don’t like about it, including the name itself which assumes that costs outweigh benefits. But I kept having this feeling that I was missing something fundamental, and today I realized what it was.

Let me start by defining and discussing the concept underlying the Social Cost of Carbon, the idea of “monetizing externalities”.

In general, the market sets a value on something, say fast-food hamburgers in paper takeaway wrappers. The burger might cost $4.95 … but there is also an “external” cost that is not included in the $4.95. This is the additional cost to the city of cleaning up the takeaway wrappers thrown out of car windows by yobbos of various flavors.

So picking up the trash is an “externality” to the cost of the burger. And we can “monetize” it by figuring out how much the extra trash costs to pick up, and dividing that by the number of burgers sold. This might give us something like three cents extra per burger that is an external cost of fast-food hamburgers.

So far, so good. Of course, we never want to just consider the costs, we also need to consider external benefits. Like external costs, these are benefits not reflected in the cost of the burger. For example, a fast-food joint brings additional traffic to the city, and those additional people will spend some money at other local businesses. And we can “monetize” this in the same way, by collecting data on the change in traffic and sales at local businesses before and after the burger joint opened. We might figure out that the value of that external benefit is five cents extra in local business per hamburger sold.

This is how a cost/benefit analysis should work. HOWEVER, and it is a big however, there are a number of pitfalls in practice, some of which I discussed in my previous post. One I did not discuss is the “Law of Unintended Consequences”, which states that there are always unintended consequences of every action no matter how sure we are of the outcome.

For example, people were greatly concerned that the introduction of snowmobiles in the Arctic would decimate the caribou population. With untiring machinery instead of dog teams, the hunters could follow the caribou wherever they went, keep up with them, catch up with a fleeing herd, run them to exhaustion … it was clear that the snow machines gave the hunters a huge advantage they hadn’t had before.

Now, that loss of caribou was projected as an “external cost” of the introduction of the snow machine … unexpectedly, however, caribou populations actually increased after the introduction of snow machines.

In hindsight the reason was obvious … snow machines run on gasoline, and dog teams run on … caribou meat …

So what was seen by everyone as an external cost turned out to be an external benefit.

To bring this back to the SCC, increasing CO2 is known to have caused a “greening” of the earth. Current CO2 levels are far below optimal for plants, so increasing CO2 yields more plant growth, the “greening” in question.

This has been measured from satellites, and is on the order of a 10% increase in plant productivity.

in the previous post I’d done a rough estimate of the effect of this known and measured 10% “greening” on human production of food and fiber. Total human food and fiber production is about $10 trillion (10E+12) US dollars per year. Thus the increased production due to CO2 is on the order of a trillion dollars per year.

Now, this is an estimate of an ongoing year-after-year external BENEFIT of increased atmospheric CO2 based on satellite measurements of chlorophyll as well as greenhouse experiments showing increased growth with increased CO2.

Which brings me to the SCC, the social cost of carbon. On the benefit side, we can start with a trillion dollars in increased production based on satellite measurements and greenhouse experiments. But what about the costs?

As far as I know, there is not one cost in all of their accounting which can objectively and scientifically be ascribed to increased CO2.

Yes, we have a theory about the relationship of CO2 and temperature … but the best computer models of that theory have failed spectacularly at forecasting the future. It’s curious to me. People understand that computers have not allowed stock brokers to outguess the stock market. But they still think that computers can outguess the climate, which is far more complex. In any case, to date the best models of the theory have not yielded true predictions of the future.

But it is worse than that. None of their claims are based on the past. All of their costs are the calculated present values of imagined future events. The chain of untested assumptions is quite long. Here is the chain:

Their so-called “costs” are based on what they think carbon dioxide MIGHT do to the temperature at some unknown future time. These in turn lead to guesses about what that imagined temperature rise MIGHT have as knock-on effects. In addition, the “costs” are also based on the future date on which said imagined knock-on effect MIGHT happen, the actual costs that MIGHT be associated with that effect, and a discount rate that MIGHT match the actual future rate.

So we have five separate chained predictions about the future.

  1. How much CO2 will affect the future temperature.
  2. When and at what speed that future temperature effect becomes visible.
  3. What the effects of that predicted temperature rise at that predicted timing and rate will be on everything from Animals to Zooplankton.
  4. What the future costs of the predicted effects from the predicted temperature rise at that predicted timing and rate will be, and finally
  5. What future discount rate will be used to convert to present value those predicted future costs of the predicted effects from the predicted temperature rise at that predicted timing and rate.

The result of all of this is that on the benefits side we have measured observable current benefits.

And on the other side we have an estimated present value based on the predicted future discount rate of a predicted future cost of a predicted future effect of a predicted future temperature rise at a predicted future timing and rate.

And as a result of this uber-subjective process, various scientific authorities making various predictions have gotten results ranging from negative and zero to $1500 per tonne of carbon. That’s not science, that’s throwing darts.

apples-and-oranges

This is what I meant by monetizing apples and oranges.

On one side we have an observable present benefit.

On the other side we have an imagined present cost based on five separate independent chained predictions of the future.

I say that it is not valid to compare those two values directly..

w.

 

17 thoughts on “Monetizing Apples And Oranges

  1. Another prediction that is needed to produce their SCC is a guess at the future rate of human CO2 emissions and the assumption that those emissions are the cause for the increase in the atmospheric content of CO2. So the whole enterprise is based on biased guesses without data to support even the assumptions used. I personally think that some new energy sources are on the near horizon (see Brilliant Light Power and Lawrenceville Plasma Physics) that will take over much of the fossil fuel use by being more affordable and less centralized.

    Like

  2. If one were to graph human life expectancy and wealth over time there would be a major hockey stick upturn about say 1870 and continuing. One could advance the argument that CO2 causes prosperity, longevity and wealth. Of course, one would be immediately condemned for using such an obviously flawed attempt at correlation and causation. The same correlation should appear when looking solely at carbon fuels such as coal and hydrocarbons, major contributors to CO2. Or you could go to metalworking and the Bessemer furnace and the advent of steel and aluminum and reach the same conclusion. An observant academic might classify these events under the heading of industrial revolution. The implied conclusion is that increasing longevity and prosperity is causing climate change and must cease. Malthus, anyone?

    So, in computing the SCC, is there value to longevity and prosperity, and how would it be valued?

    And once you start on that SCC calculation, does integrity require you to also evaluate alternatives such as nuclear power, as well as the solar and wind alternatives?

    Carry on, fire when ready, great fun ahead.

    Liked by 3 people

  3. Terry Jay December 25, 2016 at 9:47 pm

    So, in computing the SCC, is there value to longevity and prosperity, and how would it be valued?

    Not AFAIK.

    And once you start on that SCC calculation, does integrity require you to also evaluate alternatives such as nuclear power, as well as the solar and wind alternatives?

    I don’t start on the SCC calculation because I greatly mistrust the monetizing of unknown future events. Cost/benefit analyses of externalities can be valid, as in my hamburger example above. It is valid because it uses measurable present costs and measurable present benefits.

    But doing a cost/benefit analysis using the value of some future event that may or may not occur? Yes, you can use something like the DICE model, but as I showed above, the value is entirely dependent on very subjective evaluations of the probability, timing, discount rate, knock-on effects, and amount of future events.

    Thanks and regards,

    w.

    Like

    • “So, in computing the SCC, is there value to longevity and prosperity, and how would it be valued?

      Not AFAIK.”

      More taxes received for longer periods, by governments?

      Like

    • Given the hard evidence of significant improvement in prosperity and longevity occurring at the same time as the increase in CO2, this is hardly a future event. Most people regard increased prosperity and longevity as a positive net good thing.

      If the calculation is along the lines of What Good Things Have Actually Occurred, and we point to Greening, then surely we must include prosperity and longevity. There is ample evidence that increasing CO2 and Warmth have been beneficial. No need to speculate about the future. Leave the speculation to those who rely on models, Garbage in, Gospel out.

      Like

  4. Willis, once again congrats on a clearly presented argument! Your caribou / snow mobile analogy is simply elegant. I think our experience in Oz with cane toads is also instructive.
    As a small farmer in an area of South Western Australia which has experienced reduced rainfall over the last 5 or 6 decades (possibly due to intensive land clearing post WWs 1 & 2), the importance of increased CO2 is considered by me as being generally positive in terms of the stoichiometric relationship between CO2 & water, the production of higher yielding crops and a resultant increased disease and pest resistance due to higher “sugar” levels.
    My “guess” is that temperature will not be a significant result of increased CO2 and that the benefit to the food chain, from phytoplankton on, will be hopefully observable & measurable.
    We have just experienced quite a severe winter with widespread frost damage to crops in some areas east of here but with an overall increase in total tonnage perhaps due to well timed rain events over the growing season.
    At this point in time I regard the determination of the SCC as being little more than exercises in actuarial wankery!
    Cheers,

    Dave

    Like

  5. If we put the crystal ball aside, how much were actual “social costs (or benefits) of carbon” incurred in years 2000-2015? Are there hard numbers available?

    Like

  6. Do typical current SCC take into account that substituting non-CO2 energy production for current fossil fuel methods will result in less reliable energy availability, which will have negative impacts on economic activity, not to mention quality of life?

    Liked by 1 person

  7. Your 10% increased plant productivity at 400 ppm suggests that if we really were successful in cutting CO2 to 350 or even the pre-industrial 280 ppm, it would take a lot more crop land to feed us all. On the other hand, if CO2 keeps rising, the increased productivity would reduce pressure to burn down rain forests and plow ever more marginal lands. True environmentalists should love CO2 for that.

    Of course to preserve the wild spaces we have to stop burning ethanol (with questionable net CO2 impact anyway) and palm oil.

    Liked by 1 person

  8. Pingback: Monetizing Apples And Oranges | Skating on the underside of the ice | Cranky Old Crow

  9. For example, a fast-food joint brings additional traffic to the city, and those additional people will spend some money at other local businesses.

    Sounds like the positive externality posited by sports clubs when asking for taxpayer handouts to pay for a new stadium.

    Like

  10. Pingback: The Recursive Cost Of Carbon | Watts Up With That?

  11. Pingback: Cost Of Carbon | US Issues

  12. Pingback: The Economic Cost of the Social Cost of Carbon | Skating Under The Ice

  13. Pingback: The Economic Cost Of The Social Cost Of Carbon | Watts Up With That?

You are invited to add your comments. Please QUOTE THE EXACT WORDS YOU ARE DISCUSSING so we can all be clear on your subject.